Review 2A Key#
by Professor Throckmorton
for Time Series Econometrics
W&M ECON 408/PUBP 616
Slides
VAR#
Linearization#
In a model with power utility and a one-period asset with gross return \(R_t\), the dynamic equilibrium condition looks like \(c_t^{-\sigma} = \beta R_{t+1} c_{t+1}^{-\sigma}\), where \(c\) is consumption. Linearize that equation.
Answer:
Take natural log of both sides
\[\begin{align*} c_t^{-\sigma} &= \beta R_{t+1} c_{t+1}^{-\sigma} \\ \rightarrow -\sigma \log(c_t) &= \log \beta + \log(R_{t+1}) - \sigma \log(c_{t+1}) \end{align*}\]Define \(\log(x_t/\bar{x}) \equiv \hat{x}_t\) and substract off steady-state (i.e., long-run equilibrium)
\[\begin{align*} -\sigma \log(c_t) &= \log \beta + \log(R_{t+1}) - \sigma \log(c_{t+1}) \\ - [ -\sigma \log(\bar{c}) &= \log \beta + \log(\bar{R}) - \sigma \log(\bar{c})] \\ \rightarrow -\sigma \hat{c}_t &= \hat{R}_{t+1} - \sigma \hat{c}_{t+1} \end{align*}\]
Structural VAR#
The following is a linearized New Keynesian monetary policy model with variables for output, \(y\), inflation, \(\pi\), and the interest rate \(i\). Map it to a structural VAR.
Answer:
Identification#
Write down a bivariate VAR(\(1\)) where the coefficient matrix on the shocks has been recursively identified (e.g., via a Cholesky decomposition). Why and how does the ordering of the variables matter?
Answer:
The ordering of the variables determines which variable is independent of the other’s shock within a time period. Here since \(y_t\) appears first, shocks to \(x_t\) do not affect \(y_t\), i.e., \(y_t\) is indepedent from (or orthogonal to) shocks to \(x_t\).
Cholesky Decomposition#
Suppose you decompose the matrix \(\mathbf{A}\) into \(\mathbf{A} = \mathbf{L} \mathbf{L}'\), where
What was \(\mathbf{A}\)?
Answer:
VECM#
Rank#
Suppose
Is \(\mathbf{A}\) full rank? Why or why not?
Answer: It is not full rank because Row 3 equals Row 1 plus Row 2, i.e., it is a linear combination of other rows.
Cointegration#
Suppose you observe the following data
\(t\) |
\(y_t\) |
\(x_t\) |
---|---|---|
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
7 |
5 |
7 |
7 |
6 |
9 |
9 |
7 |
11 |
10 |
8 |
13 |
12 |
9 |
15 |
15 |
Do \(y_t\) and \(x_t\) appear to be stationary? Why or why not?
What conditions need to be satisified so that \(y_t\) and \(x_t\) are cointegrated?
Do you think \(y_t\) and \(x_t\) are cointegrated? Why or why not?
Answer:
Both \(y_t\) and \(x_t\) are increasing over time, so they do not appear stationary, although the sample is very short
Both \(y_t\) and \(x_t\) must be non-stationary, I(\(1\)), and there must exist some linear combination, \(y_t - \beta x_t\), that is stationary.
Subtracting \(x_t\) from \(y_t\) yields a sequence that alternates between \(-1\), \(0\), and \(1\), which might be stationary because there might be a stable mean and variance
Cointegration Test#
What are the null and alternative hypotheses of the Johansen cointegration test?
Suppose you are testing for the number of cointegrating relationships among 3 variables. Describe how to to do that with the Johansen conintegration test.
Answer:
Suppose there are \(r_0 = 0\) cointegrating relationships
Null Hypothesis: \(H_0: r \leq r_0\) (i.e., the number of cointegrating relationships \(\leq r_0\))
Alternative Hypothesis: \(H_A: r > r_0\)
I would put a loop around the above hypothesis test and increment \(r_0 = 1,2,3\) until it fails to reject the null, i.e., there is evidence to support that the number of cointegration relationships is \(r = r_0\).
VECM Model#
Suppose in an estimated bivariate VECM with variables \(y\) and \(x\) (in that order), the cointegrating vector is \([1, -3]\) and the loading on \(y\) is \(\alpha_1 = -0.5\)
What is the long-run relationship between \(y\) and \(x\)?
Suppose at some point in time \(y_t = 6\) and \(x_t = 1.5\). What is the error correcion term at \(t\)? Is the system in long-run equilibrium?
Interpret the sign and magnitude of \(\alpha_1 = -0.5\).
Answer:
The long-run relationship is \(y_t - 3x_t\), i.e., that linear combination produces a stationary time series.
At \((y_t,x_t) = (6,1.5)\) the \(ECT_t = 6 - 3\times 1.5 = 1.5\) is not zero, so the system is not in long-run equilibrium.
\(\alpha_1 < 0\) means that changes in \(y_t\) returns the system back to the long-run equilibrium and the magnitude determines the speed (e.g., \(50\%\) in one period) at which it returns to the long-run equilibrium.