Goods Market¶

by Professor Throckmorton
for Intermediate Macro
W&M ECON 304
Slides

Introduction¶

  • In Part 1, we looked at different ways of accounting for GDP and comparing GDP per capita and its growth rate across countries.
  • The Solow growth model made dynamic predictions about income per worker given assumptions about the nature of production, capital, and investment.
  • In that model, we focused on the effects of capital accumulation, technological growth, and the savings rate on income per worker over the long run.
  • While $Y = C + I$, the growth model was about explaining investment, not consumption.
  • In Part 2, we will abstract from capital accumulation and turn our attention to the short run, first focusing on household consumption.

Q: Why Consumption?

BEA, National Data, NIPA, Table 1.1.5

  • The consumption share of GDP is the largest component, larger than investment, government spending, and net exports.
  • The consumption share of GDP has increased over time.
  • Of course this is quite different between high and low income countries, but high income countries generally have a large share of consumption to GDP.

Consumption Function¶

  • Assume that aggregate consumption is a function of disposable income

$$ C = c_0 + c_1 \times (Y - T) $$

  • $Y$ is income, while $T$ is net tax revenue. Thus, $Y-T$ is disposable income available to households.
  • Note: $T$ is net tax revenue because some households receive transfers from the government, e.g., Social Security payments and medical expenses paid via Medicare

Parameters

  • $c_1$ quantifies the fraction of current disposable income consumed by households
    • In the language of micro, we might call it the "consumption elasticity of disposable income"
    • In the language of macro, most people call it the "marginal propensity to consume" (MPC)
    • If there were low and high income households in the model, which do you think would have a higher average MPC?
  • $c_0$ is all consumption that is independent of current disposable income. Imagine if $Y-T = 0$, then
    • households could dissave and consume out of their wealth, or
    • households could borrow against their wealth or future income to consume.

Aggregate Expenditure¶

  • In Ch. 2, the expenditure approach to GDP is $Y = C + I + G + NX$
  • In the Solow growth model, we abstract from $G$ and $NX$ and just had $Y = C + I$
  • In Part 2, we'll work with a closed economy but consider changes in government spending, so $Y = C + I + G$
  • But we need to separate the expenditure (i.e., demand) side apart from the supply side, so let $Y$ be aggregate supply/output and aggregate expenditure is

$$ Z = C + I + G $$

  • In equilibrium, $Y = Z$, but there are disequilibria where $Y \neq Z$

Disequilibrium $\rightarrow$ Equilibrium

  • If $Y > Z$, there is excess supply

    • Inventories would accumulate
    • Firms would probably decrease production $\downarrow Y$
  • If $Y < Z$, there is excess expenditure

    • Inventories would deplete
    • Firms would probably increase production $\uparrow Y$
  • Either way, there is a tendency for $Y$ to move toward $Z$, and thus $Y = Z$ is an equilibrium.

Endogneous Variables¶

  • So far, the model has variables $Y, C, I, G, T$
  • We've assumed $C$ is a function of $Y$ and in equilibrium, $Y = C + I + G$, i.e., $Y$ is a function of $C$. These are known as endogenous variables.
  • However, we have not assumed functions for $I,G,T$ (yet). They are variables and could change, but they do not explicitly depend on $Y$ or $C$ (yet). These are known as exogenous variables.
  • We can also treat parameters as exogenous variables, e.g., in the growth model we considered the effects of an increasing in the savings rate (a parameter).
  • For example, we could consider a financial crisis that reduces asset prices a reduction in househould wealth that is reflected by a decrease in $c_0$. Another way to think of that is falling consumer confidence.

The Multiplier¶

  • The goods market in equilibrium has 3 equations
    1. $C = c_0 + c_1 \times (Y - T)$ (a behavioral equation)
    2. $Z = C + I + G$ (an accounting identity)
    3. $Y = Z$ (an equilibrium condition)
  • The main prediction this model makes is that an exogenous change in expenditure is multiplied into a larger endogenous change in equilibrium income/output.
  • That result is known as Income Multiplication (or the Keynesian Multiplier).

Multiplier Example

  • Suppose an Infrastructure Spending Bill is passed, or $G \uparrow$ by $\Delta G$
  • Aggregate expenditure, $Z$, directly increases by $\Delta G$
  • Firms see higher demand for their outputs, e.g., increased orders for steel, cement, and construction equipment and vehicles, so they increase production, $Y \uparrow$ also by $\Delta G$ (on impact)
  • Households receive more income and they consume an additional $c_1 \Delta G$
  • But $C$ is part of $Z$, so the loop repeats, i.e, the initial change in government spending multiplies into additional income over time.
Multiplier Step $\Delta Y$ $\Delta C$
0 $\Delta G$ $c_1\Delta G$
1 $c_1\Delta G$ $c_1^2\Delta G$
2 $c_1^2\Delta G$ $c_1^3\Delta G$
3 $c_1^3\Delta G$ $c_1^4\Delta G$
... ... ...
  • Since we've assumed $0 < c_1 < 1$, each additional step is adding a smaller amount to income/output.

  • Add up the $\Delta Y$ column and we get

    $$ \Delta Y = \Delta G + c_1\Delta G +c_1^2\Delta G +c_1^3\Delta G + \cdots \\ = \Delta G (1 + c_1 +c_1^2 +c_1^3 + \cdots) \\ = \frac{\Delta G}{1-c_1} $$

  • In other words, the multiplication process is represented by a geometric series (see the Wiki on that).

  • E.g., suppose $\Delta G = \$1T$ and $c_1 = 0.25$, then

    $$ \Delta Y = \frac{\Delta G}{1-c_1} = \frac{\$1T}{0.75} = \$1.33T $$

  • $1/(1-c_1)$ is known as the government spending multiplier in this model.

Equilibrium Output¶

  • The goods market makes predictions about output/income, $Y$.

  • Q: How do changes in exogenous variables affect $Y$?

  • Combining the goods markets equations (imposing that the model is in equilibrium)

    $$ Y = c_0 + c_1(Y-T) + I + G $$

  • Solving for equilibrium output, $Y$

    $$ Y = \frac{1}{1-c_1} \left(c_0 - c_1 T + I + G \right) $$

  • $c_1, c_0, T, I, G$ are all exogenous parameters/variables at the moment.

Other Multipliers

  • From the solution for equilbrium output, we can see the government spending multiplier (which is the same as the earlier example)

    $$ \Delta Y = \frac{1}{1-c_1} \Delta G $$

  • An exogenous change in investment has the same multiplier

    $$ \Delta Y = \frac{1}{1-c_1} \Delta I $$

  • However, an exogenous change in net taxes has a different multiplier because households first choose consumption vs. savings and a change in net taxes has the opposite effect on consumption (than a change in governement spending).

    $$ \Delta Y = \frac{-c_1}{1-c_1} \Delta T $$

Goods Market Graph¶

  • The goods market graph will show output, $Y$, vs expenditure, $Z$.
  • Blanchard, Macroeconomics (9th Edition, 2025) introduces new notation for a graph of aggregate expenditure and calls it $ZZ$.
  • $ZZ$ differentiates the aggregate expenditure function from particular realizations of aggregate expenditure that we label as just $Z$ on the vertical axis.
No description has been provided for this image
No description has been provided for this image
  • If output is below equilibrium, then expenditure exceeds output, $Z_{low} > Y_{low}$.
  • In micro language, we would call that a shortage. But in macro, excess expenditure could be met with inventories (i.e., past production).
  • Excess expenditure creates an unplanned decrease in inventories, which is an incentive for firms to increase output.

Experiment¶

  • Suppose $G\uparrow$ from $G_0$ to $G_1$.
  • An exogenous increase in $G$ will shift up the $ZZ$ curve.
  • That creates excess expenditure, which depletes inventories.
  • Firms increase production until the new equilibrium is reached.
No description has been provided for this image

Savings¶

  • Define private saving as disposable income not consumed, $S_{private} \equiv Y - T - C$.
  • Define public saving as net tax revenue minus government spending, $S_{public} \equiv T - G$
  • Note that in a goods market equilibrium $Y = C + I + G$.
  • Subtract $T$ from both sides and move $C$ to the left hand side

$$ Y - T - C = I + G - T \\ \rightarrow S_{private} = I - (T - G) \\ \rightarrow I = S_{private} + S_{public} \equiv S_{national} $$

  • Thus, in equilibrium investment equals saving.